Overview of the College Cost Reduction Act (H.R. 6951): What it Means for Medical Students
- Nate Swanson
- Apr 30
- 14 min read
Updated: May 19

H.R. 6951 was introduced by Rep. Virginia Foxx (R–NC) on January 11, 2024, as a “reauthorization” of the Higher Education Act to “lower the cost of tuition and make federal student aid more sustainable”. It has broad Republican support (over 150 cosponsors in the 118th Congress congress.gov) but faces a challenging path in the new Congress. The bill’s stated goals are to curb tuition inflation, simplify loan repayment, and make institutions share more risk with taxpayers. For example, ACE summarizes that it would double Pell Grant funding for on-time juniors and seniors in high-ROI bachelor’s programs, and eliminate interest capitalization on federal loans (so borrowers only pay interest as scheduled, effectively a 10‑year standard plan) acenet.edu. It would also update financial reporting for colleges, drop certain ED regulations (like Gainful Employment and “financial value transparency” rules), and create a data-driven earnings metric to judge program value.
On the other hand, H.R. 6951 cuts or limits several aid programs: it terminates Graduate PLUS and Parent PLUS loans, tightens annual and aggregate loan limits, and eliminates programs like FSEOG (campus-based grants) acenet.edu. For instance, under the bill an undergraduate could borrow at most $50K (unsubsidized) + $23K (subsidized) [with very limited exception to ~$150K total] acenet.edu, while graduate students could borrow up to ~$100K and professional students (e.g. medical students) up to ~$150K (with a hard cap of $200K total) acenet.edu. The bill also replaces existing income-driven repayment (IDR) plans for new loans with a simplified 10‑year-equivalent plan cbo.gov. Importantly, it requires institutions to pay if their former students default or fail to repay; each college would make risk-sharing payments based on the cohort’s unpaid loan balance acenet.edu.
In summary, H.R. 6951 mixes new student aid (more Pell) with stricter borrowing limits and institutional accountability acenet.eduacenet.edu. The House Education & Workforce Committee reported the bill in November 2024 (H.Rept. 118-739) congress.gov, but it has not passed the House as of April 2025. Its fate will depend on legislative priorities, with Republicans championing it as a cost-cutting measure and Democrats criticizing cuts to aid.
Possible Scenarios if the Bill Passes
If enacted, H.R. 6951 would shake up higher education financing. Here are some plausible scenarios:
Incentives to lower tuition: Colleges facing risk-sharing fees and a value-added metric might be pressured to curb tuition growth. For example, the Heritage Action analysis notes that requiring schools to “have financial skin in the game” should “incentiviz[e] them to lower costs” heritageaction.com. Under this scenario, programs with poor graduate earnings would shrink or improve, and universities would invest more in programs that lead to jobs. Supporters argue that linking aid to outcomes (as through the PROMISE grants and Earnings-Price Ratio) would generally “put downward pressure on tuition” crfb.org. Modest borrowers might benefit: doubling Pell for juniors/seniors could help reduce undergraduate debt for timely graduates acenet.edu, and eliminating interest capitalization means borrowers pay less interest over time (saving money compared to longer IDR plans).
Shifts in student behavior: Facing tighter loan caps, some students might choose lower-cost schools or accelerated paths. Premed undergraduates, for instance, might double-major in high-ROI STEM fields (to capture the enhanced Pell benefits) and finish in four years. Fewer students may take out large loans for expensive degrees, potentially reducing total debt levels. In general, the bill could discourage “excessive borrowing” crfb.org and push some students toward scholarships, work-study, or living at home.
Institutional adjustments: Colleges may change their strategies. Some might cut costs or eliminate underperforming programs to avoid penalties. Others might raise prices elsewhere or target wealthier students (or out-of-state tuition) to make up revenue. For example, if federal aid for need-based students shrinks, schools could shift costs onto those with parent wealth or increase non-tuition fees. Data transparency (e.g. updated College Scorecard and net-price calculators) would allow students to compare programs, possibly amplifying competition on cost/value.
Negative consequences for some fields: Conversely, programs with traditionally low earnings (like many liberal arts or social sciences) could be hit hard by the earnings-based rules. These programs might shrink or close if they trigger large risk payments. In extreme cases, a college could refuse to enroll students in high-risk programs. Also, reduced aid (like cutting FSEOG or PLUS loans) could exclude some low-income or nontraditional students who relied on that support. For example, eliminating Graduate PLUS forces grad/prof students to rely only on capped Stafford loans acenet.edu, meaning future doctors or PhDs could face funding gaps.
Response of colleges and families: If tuition still rises, families might seek private loans or out-of-pocket financing, or defer college. Some experts worry that simply restricting federal aid could hurt students more than schools: widespread loan caps risk pushing costs onto students’ plates (via private loans or higher-interest debt). In fact, past research finds that every expansion of loan eligibility has often been matched by higher tuition bestcolleges.commises.org, so removing aid could play out in unpredictable ways.
In short, optimistic scenarios see colleges trimming costs and debt loads easing for families, while pessimistic scenarios see access shriveling for some students and financial strains persisting. The real outcome will hinge on how elastic student demand is and how institutions actually respond. Studies of past price elasticity suggest demand is fairly inelastic (a 10% price hike might cut attendance by only 4% reed.edu), so colleges might not lose many students even if they raise tuition to cover lost aid.
Unintended Consequences
Legislation often has side-effects. Potential unintended outcomes of H.R. 6951 include:
Program closures or consolidation: Risk-sharing could particularly punish institutions with high default rates (e.g. many for-profit colleges). Indeed, for-profits account for ~40% of defaults but only ~10% of enrollment en.wikipedia.org. If such schools must reimburse large defaults, many might exit the market or merge to survive. Even non-profit colleges might tighten admission criteria to protect default stats, potentially reducing access.
Tuition shifting: Some critics warn colleges will find ways around the law. For instance, if federal aid is restricted, schools might raise tuition even more to compensate (knowing students can take private loans or draw on savings). In fact, Reagan-era Education Secretary William Bennett’s “loan cushion” hypothesis is cited by research: one study found that 102% of the 106% tuition increase (1987–2010) was driven by federal loan changes mises.org. In other words, guaranteed loans may have enabled schools to keep raising prices because students could borrow the difference. Thus, removing subsidies could in theory slow inflation, but there is also a risk colleges simply pocketed federal aid instead of cutting tuition.
Field-of-study distortions: Federal policies often shape career choices. If aid favors “high-ROI” majors and graduation rates, colleges may steer students toward those fields even more strongly. While this could improve workforce alignment, it might inadvertently devalue important but lower-paying careers (e.g. education, the arts, social work). Students interested in those paths could find both less aid and fewer open slots.
Equity concerns: Some changes could hit disadvantaged students. Eliminating campus-based aid and Plus loans removes sources that many low-income, rural, or older students rely on. If borrowing is capped, poorer students might be forced to work long hours or delay school, potentially lowering completion rates. This outcome would oppose the bill’s stated goal of educational access.
Administrative burdens: Complex new rules (median cost calculations, risk formulas) could saddle financial aid offices with red tape. Some colleges might divert resources to compliance rather than students. Accreditation bodies note that while the goal of affordability is shared, H.R. 6951 “in its current form” faced concerns from regional accreditor commissions msche.org – perhaps due to new requirements around program metrics and reviews.
Positive spillovers: On the positive side, some unintended benefits might occur. Greater transparency and accountability could spark innovations in cost control (e.g. competency-based education, community partnerships). The bill’s emphasis on completion might encourage support services that help students graduate on time, which could indirectly lower costs per degree. In theory, by aligning incentives with outcomes, the legislation might lead to smarter spending at colleges.
Overall, H.R. 6951’s far-reaching changes could produce a mix of surprises. Proponents hope the “skin in the game” rules will force colleges to rethink spending, but dissenters worry the pain of reduced aid could outweigh the gains.
Immediate Implications for Medical Students
Medical students (and applicants) would be among the most affected by H.R. 6951. The bill eliminates the Graduate PLUS loan entirely acenet.edu. Currently, medical students routinely use Grad PLUS to cover tuition and living expenses above the standard Stafford limits. Under the new scheme, MD/DO students could borrow only up to the professional aggregate cap ($150,000 total) acenet.edu. For context, the AAMC reports most MD graduates borrow well over $200K aamc.org. With Grad PLUS gone, many future doctors would face funding gaps. The Osteopathic medical association (AACOM) warns that a “$200,000 cap on federal loans per borrower” and PLUS elimination would “create significant financial barriers” for medical students aacom.org. In practice, med students would need to rely on unsubsidized Stafford loans (up to ~$100K for grad students) and possibly private loans or out-of-pocket funds to pay the rest.
There are a few potential upsides for medical borrowers: the bill removes interest capitalization on all loans acenet.edu, which modestly reduces total interest costs for those who don’t repay quickly. It also replaces IDR plans with a standard 10-year plan (or equivalent new plan) cbo.gov, which limits the total repayment amount to principal+10-year interest. For some MDs this means faster payoff if they choose to pay more aggressively, though it cuts off any future interest forgiveness beyond that.
However, the net impact for medical students is largely negative. The loss of Grad PLUS and new loan caps make financing med school much tougher. Many may need alternative strategies (saving aggressively in college, working, scholarships, or private loans). The AACOM specifically urges students to “act today to protect Grad PLUS loans” and “oppose federal borrowing caps” aacom.org. In short, under the bill med students would shoulder more risk: they could borrow less from federal sources and potentially graduate with less debt forgiveness. Medical schools themselves would have “skin in the game,” but since doctor graduates rarely default (they earn high incomes), this mainly means those schools might pay into the risk fund even as their students struggle with tighter borrowing limits.
Austrian Economics: Federal Aid and Tuition Pricing
From an Austrian-economic perspective, the College Cost Reduction Act touches on classic debates over credit and inflation. Austrian economics defines “inflation” as expansion of credit or the money supply, not merely rising prices. Applying this to education, Austrians argue that when the government injects credit (through loans and grants), it fuels higher prices in that sector. In other words, generous federal aid makes colleges and universities feel confident that students can pay, so institutions raise tuition.
This view is widely known as the “Bennett Hypothesis.” Reagan’s Secretary of Education Bill Bennett famously warned that “schools will use the aid like a cushion for the next tuition increase.” Empirical studies back this up: one NBER study concluded that 102% of the 1987–2010 tuition rise was due to federal loan program changes mises.org. Another analysis found that schools participating in Title IV aid programs charged 78% more than similar schools without federal aid mises.org. Likewise, a BestColleges report notes that once Sallie Mae and loan guarantees appeared, “colleges increased tuition knowing banks were eager to issue student loans” bestcolleges.com. Even researchers have stated plainly that “increasing borrowing limits drives tuition increases” en.wikipedia.org.
In supply-demand terms, Austrian economists would say that federal student loans shift the demand curve outward (more people can afford tuition), and because many students view college as a necessity (an inelastic demand), the net effect is a higher equilibrium price (tuition). Studies of elasticity bear this out: an early estimate found an own-price elasticity of demand around –0.44 for all four-year colleges reed.edu (so a 10% price increase only cuts enrollment by about 4%). Thus, giving students more credit doesn’t proportionally raise enrollment; instead, schools capture most of the extra spending by hiking tuition.
Under this theory, repealing aid (as H.R. 6951 largely does for grad/parent loans) should relieve inflationary pressure. However, because demand is relatively inelastic, college prices might not fall automatically; instead, total tuition growth might slow or stabilize. Critics of the Austrian view point to other factors (state funding cuts, Baumol’s cost disease, administrative bloat) as drivers of price. But proponents of H.R. 6951 clearly lean Austrian: by cutting subsidies and adding accountability, they intend to force a market correction in pricing.
Whether this will happen is debated. In practice, some economists have cast doubt on credit alone as the culprit. For example, some research finds that reducing bureaucracy and improving efficiency could also slow tuition. Nevertheless, the Austrian analysis helps explain why many conservatives support measures like loan limits and risk-sharing: they view them as removing the “artificial” credit that allowed prices to inflate unchecked.
Federal guarantees of student loans began in the 1960s and 1970s (symbolized by the Sallie Mae building above). Critics argue that once loans became easy to obtain, colleges steadily raised prices to capture that money bestcolleges.commises.org.
Historical Context: Tuition After Loan Guarantees
The current debate echoes history. Federal involvement in student loans dates to the 1965 Higher Education Act, which created Guaranteed Student Loans luminafoundation.org. The goal was to expand access for low- and middle-income students. In 1972, Congress established the Student Loan Marketing Association (Sallie Mae) to buy those loans and inject more capital into the system luminafoundation.org. Over the ensuing decades, tuition soared. For example, average annual tuition at public four-year colleges rose more than 75% in real terms every decade from the 1970s through the 2000s educationdata.org. Many observers link that rise to loan guarantees: one recent article notes that when California’s Reagan expanded loans and Sallie Mae backed lending, “colleges increased tuition knowing banks were eager to issue loans” bestcolleges.com.
Research also shows that schools able to tap federal aid often charge much more. A study by Claudia Goldin and Lawrence Katz found that “Title IV” (federal aid) institutions charge 78% more than similar non–Title IV schools (which can’t offer federal aid) mises.org. Likewise, the overwhelming majority of student debt today is from federal loans mises.org. Proponents of the Bennett Hypothesis argue that the tuition explosion in the 1980s–2000s was caused by the rise of federal subsidies mises.org.
It’s worth noting that other factors played a role (state disinvestment, rising faculty salaries, amenities, etc.). But the timing is striking: guaranteed loans and Pell expansions coincide with accelerating tuition. In essence, as credit availability grew, college prices followed. The College Cost Reduction Act is an attempt to reverse that trend by scaling back federal credit.
Projections: Future College and Medical School Costs
What might happen to tuition if H.R. 6951 became law? Projections are uncertain, but some analysts have weighed in. The Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget (CRFB) estimates the bill would save over $150 billion in federal outlays over 10 years crfb.org, and importantly “generally put downward pressure on tuition” crfb.org. In other words, by trimming loan subsidies and enforcing accountability, the CRFB expects slower growth in sticker prices.
However, actual tuition trends will depend on market responses. If demand remains strong and aid is cut, colleges may try to make up revenue in other ways (raising out-of-pocket fees or recruiting full-pay students). Given relatively inelastic demand (elasticity ~–0.4 reed.edu), a substantial reduction in aid might not drastically reduce enrollment, so institutions would need to accept lower revenue or trim expenses. Some skeptics argue this could mean budget cuts at colleges rather than big tuition declines.
For medical schools specifically, predictions are mixed. If MD programs lose the ability to rely on federal loans, some fear fewer applicants or higher student costs. But since there is a doctor shortage, demand is unlikely to collapse. Medical deans might respond by limiting class sizes, cutting non essential spending, or increasing philanthropy/scholarships. To the extent law forces colleges to bear some loan risk, administrators might more closely monitor program costs. Yet short-term impacts would likely be increased financial strain on med students: AACOM cautions that eliminating Grad PLUS and capping debt “would create significant financial barriers” for future physicians aacom.org. In the long run, if schools feel a revenue pinch, they might engage more in aggressive fundraising or cost-cutting (e.g. freezing tuition, reducing services) to avoid passing costs onto students.
In sum, college costs may grow more slowly with H.R. 6951, especially if multiple reforms work in tandem (as CRFB suggests). But prices may not fall and could still outpace inflation if colleges find other revenue sources. Medical school tuition, which already far exceeds general college costs, might remain high unless structural changes (like new funding models or widespread scholarships) occur. In any case, observers agree that students and families should not assume tuition will drop substantially on its own; proactive financial planning will still be crucial.
Political Outlook: Will the Bill Pass?
The likelihood of H.R. 6951 becoming law is uncertain. In the 118th Congress (2023–2024) Republicans held the House, and Foxx’s committee advanced the bill (it was placed on the calendar in Nov. 2024 congress.gov). However, as of early 2025 the balance of power shifted: the House now has a Democratic majority and the Senate a narrow Republican majority. Neither chamber has taken up a college-reform bill yet.
Key factors affecting the bill’s fate include:
Partisan support: House Republicans generally favor the bill’s approach. Heritage Action, a conservative advocacy group, endorses H.R. 6951 as a “real solution” to rising tuition heritageaction.com. They argue that removing “unlimited government-backed loans” and forcing institutions to pay for defaults will align incentives properly heritageaction.com. On the other side, most Democrats oppose dismantling aid programs. Educational and student groups have raised alarms. The American Council on Education (ACE) notes the bill has both “positive” and “concerning” provisions acenet.edu, while accreditors have formally opposed it “in its current form” despite agreeing on affordability goals msche.org. Broadly speaking, Republicans champion accountability and cost-control, whereas Democrats emphasize preserving aid and access.
Budgetary context: Because H.R. 6951 is framed as saving taxpayer money (CBO scored ~$185B in deficit reduction crfb.org), it could be considered in budget reconciliation. However, reconciliation requires same-party control of Congress and presidential support. In 2025 the White House (Democrat) is unlikely to back legislation that cuts aid for borrowers (e.g. eliminating Grad PLUS). Any attempt to include parts of this bill in a reconciliation package would face stiff hurdles.
Institutional lobbying: Colleges and accrediting bodies wield influence. Many universities oppose risk-sharing (fearing liability) and loss of subsidies. They may lobby against the bill or seek amendments. By contrast, some student-loan reform groups and fiscal conservatives push for similar ideas.
Public opinion: Voters broadly want affordable college, but opinions diverge on solutions. The technical nature of risk-sharing and loan limits may be hard to sell. Unless there is a political deal (for example, pairing Pell expansion with loan cuts), the bill may stall.
In short, while H.R. 6951 has momentum among House Republicans, it faces an uphill climb. It has no Senate companion currently, and President Biden has called for student debt relief rather than more restrictions. Absent significant bipartisan changes, the measure is unlikely to pass intact this session. Some elements (like Pell changes or loan reforms) might resurface in future Higher Education Act reauthorization discussions or budget bills.
Advice for Premed and Medical Students (and Families)
Given the uncertainties, students and families should prepare now. Here are practical steps and considerations:
Educate and advocate: Stay informed about legislative developments (e.g. via AAMC, AACOM, student debt organizations). AACOM urges medical students to contact Congress and oppose provisions that threaten Grad PLUS loans and impose caps aacom.org. Engaging through school chapters or professional associations can amplify student voices.
Budgeting and financial literacy: Cultivate strong money habits. Many medical schools now offer (or require) financial-planning workshops, and even use tools like AAMC’s MedLoans Organizer to track debt aamc.org. Whether or not this bill passes, understanding personal finance is critical. Create a strict budget for each year of school, tracking all loans, living expenses, and potential scholarships.
Minimize up-front costs: For premeds, application expenses add up. AAMC notes that every secondary application fee (ranging up to $200 each) and the MCAT fee ($320) can drain savings aamc.org. Use fee waivers (AAMC offers an MCAT fee assistance program) and apply judiciously to schools where you are competitive. If accepted to one school, withdraw other applications to save travel costs. These small savings reduce the need to borrow later.
Seek scholarships and grants early: Exhaust free aid first. AAMC recommends searching scholarship databases (e.g. CollegeScholarships.org, AAFP scholarships, school-specific funds) and applying widely aamc.org. Medical schools may have institutional aid or loan repayment programs (e.g. Public Service Loan Forgiveness for those entering residency in qualifying jobs). Every dollar of scholarship saved is $1 of loan avoidance.
Time your education: The proposed bill rewards timely graduation. Under H.R. 6951 juniors and seniors on-trackto finish could get double Pell Grants acenet.edu. That means completing prerequisites and degree requirements in a timely fashion can maximize financial aid. Delaying graduation (even by a semester) might not be as heavily supported.
Plan loan repayment proactively: Even if existing IDR plans change, understanding repayment options is vital. Start thinking now about Public Service Loan Forgiveness, military scholarships (like HPSP/USUHS), National Health Service Corps programs, or residency programs that offer loan repayment. Use loan calculators to model repayments under different income scenarios aamc.org. If debt is likely to be capped, aim to borrow only what you truly need, and consider paying interest or principal early if possible.
Explore cost-saving paths: Some students opt for combined degree programs (e.g. MD/PhD, which often comes with funding) or look at lower-cost medical schools (in-state publics, regional campuses). For residents, consider less expensive living situations or moonlighting to reduce debt.
Maintain academic focus: Remember that academic performance can unlock merit aid or scholarships. Strong grades and extracurriculars not only bolster residency prospects but can also lead to awards (e.g. NIH research grants or specialty society scholarships). Focus on building a profile that minimizes financial risk by attracting funding.
Stay adaptive: Rules might change. For example, if loan caps do pass, having alternative sources (family help, personal savings, income from part-time work) becomes crucial. Develop contingency plans: could you defer enrollment for a year to save money? Could you attend a less expensive school for part of your education? Be ready to pivot.
In essence, protect yourself by living below your means in school, leveraging all available aid, and advocating for policies that support students. Keep an eye on developments, consult financial aid advisors, and build a network of mentors (as recommended by AAMC aamc.org aamc.org). By staying informed and proactive, students and families can better weather policy changes like the College Cost Reduction Act, whatever its ultimate outcome.
Like this one? Check out these related articles next!
Comments